Make your work easier and more efficient installing the rrojasdatabank  toolbar ( you can customize it ) in your browser. 
Counter visits from more than 160  countries and 1400 universities (details)

The political economy of development
This academic site promotes excellence in teaching and researching economics and development, and the advancing of describing, understanding, explaining and theorizing.
About us- Castellano- Français - Dedication
Home- Themes- Reports- Statistics/Search- Lecture notes/News- People's Century- Puro Chile- Mapuche


World indicators on the environmentWorld Energy Statistics - Time SeriesEconomic inequality

Previous              Next              Contents

Trade-Related Employment For Women In Industry And Services In Developing Countries

SECTION 2: Understanding the Past: Trade and the Gender Dimension In Manufacturing


 

2.1 Overview

Development of industrial capacity is an integral part of national economic growth. Increases in agricultural productivity have been crucial to sustainable development, even where, as in East Asian countries, the strategic focus has been on non-agricultural development; but no country has so far achieved per capita income of more than US$ 1,000 on the basis of development and modernization of agriculture alone (Riedel, 1993: 420).

This paper will argue that the extent to which industrialization generates employment opportunities for women in developing countries has been determined by the trade orientation of industrial production. Industrialisation under a strategy of national autarky provides "jobs for the boys", i.e., for a male "labour aristocracy", whereas the types of industry that expand in response to foreign market opportunities in an open trading régime rely heavily on the use of female labour. In the contemporary era, no strong export performance in manufactures by any developing country has ever been secured without reliance on female labour.3

This comes about because of certain universal regularities in the composition of exports of manufactures and related patterns of labour use by gender. The breakthrough into exports of manufactures typically begins for a low-income country with exports of clothing, footwear and processed foods, followed (if diversification takes place) by production of micro-circuits and electronic products for consumer or business use. In both of these broad product categories women workers constitute the majority of the manufacturing sector workforce.

By contrast, nations that have attempted self-sufficiency in industrial production, covering both production of "light" consumer products and heavy and "continuous process" industrial plant, have tended mostly to employ male labour in the manufacturing sector. Where women have been employed they have been concentrated in the same product subsectors that first achieve international competitiveness when exports are encouraged.

This paper analyses and explains this pattern of gender specialization in industrial employment and reliance on female labour in subsectors of industry that develop export capacity.

Two fundamental questions for gender policy that arise from this situation are also addressed in this paper. The first is: does reliance on female labour persist as export capacity is deepened and diversified in later stages of development? The second is: does mobilization of women into a country's industrial labour force through growth of exports enhance women's overall position in the labour market in terms of the quality of jobs provided and in remuneration?
 

2.2 Production Structures and Employment In Industry Under Autarkic Protection Versus Export Orientation

Developing country governments have historically differed very considerably in their industrialization strategies. At the two extremes of policy are autarkic industrialization for industrial self-sufficiency, and industrialization in a fully open or relatively liberal trading régime, responding to international market demand and supplying foreign as well as local markets. Many countries have changed their policy stance over time, moving along the policy spectrum away from complete autarky towards greater openness; consequently a hybrid of policies is often found in practice, with elements from both strategies coexisting.

The underlying rationales and the policy measures used to implement different industrialization strategies are well known. Autarkic strategies, viable in their purest form only for large economies, were driven by three concerns. The first was an often nationalistic desire to establish an integrated industrial structure. The second was the belief that conditions in international markets were inherently biased against developing country producers. The bias arose either because cartels and oligopolies based in industrialized countries colluded to resist new entrants, or because trading conditions were structurally distorted, essentially as a result of demand conditions, against the kinds of primary commodities that developing country producers could supply. The third was that protection was necessary before countries could become competitive internationally. This refers to the policy of giving "infant industry" protection from established foreign producers to local businesses during their start-up period.

In principle, the goal of autarkic development was to attain complete national self-sufficiency in manufactured products by building capacity at all levels of an integrated vertical producer chain. The industrial sector was to produce the whole range of producer and consumer products, ranging from heavy basic supplies and raw materials (metals, industrial chemicals, power generation); to production of components and parts; and to production of consumer goods.

The governments of many large developing countries, especially in Latin America and South Asia, favoured autarkic industrialization, and it was of course the governing strategy in the centrally planned socialist economies. But the approach found widespread favour throughout the developing world, including the larger East Asian economies. However, autarkic industrialization proved a costly policy to governments and to the population at large. Protection allowed persistent cost inefficiencies and entailed the emergence of quasi-rents and rent-seeking behaviour by firms. Sometimes subsidies to producers were very large, as was the overpricing of consumer goods to local markets relative to international prices. The maturation of domestic producers proved elusive: vested interests emerged to defend the economic rents that could be made behind trade barriers and resisted their reduction. Another consequence of protection was that the tariff structures imposed on imports cheapened the cost of capital and encouraged more capital intensive production methods than the real local relative cost of capital and labour would have led to. On the other side, the spectacular economic success of the East Asian nations, which gave a central place to export production and succeeded in penetrating world markets to an unprecedented degree, tended to highlight the failures of the autarkic approach and to suggest that other industrialization strategies might be more successful.

For these reasons, and under the pressure of the requirement under structural adjustment programmes that governments reduce public spending, eliminate industrial subsidies and liberalize trade, which the debt crisis of the early 1980s made developing countries subject to, autarky and import substitution are now largely abandoned as the prevailing approach to industrialization in developing countries.

The alternative strategy, now so much in the ascendant worldwide, is export-oriented or export-promoting. This strategy is premised on the possibility of exploiting international comparative advantage in trade, and the idea that international competitiveness is attainable more or less immediately by developing country producers in certain manufacturing product categories. These categories are identified on the basis of the factor proportions used in production. In conformity with developing countries" abundance of labour resources and scarcity of capital, compared to developed countries, products made by relatively labour intensive methods are expected to be internationally competitive.

An export-oriented industrial strategy is put into effect through a set of macro-economic policies, which typically include devaluation of the local currency (making product sales in foreign markets more attractive), lower tariffs on imported materials and components, improvements in the administrative treatment of exporters, such as "fast track" provision of operating permits, and sometimes favourable tax treatment for exporters by way of special tax holidays, etc.

Producers based in export processing zones (EPZs) often benefited from a complete set of such preferences, but they also applied to other locations to a greater or lesser extent (World Bank, 1992). EPZs were set up largely to attract foreign investment, for provision of capital, market expertise and/or technology, according to the particular needs of the local economy (ILO/UNCTC, 1988). EPZs have assumed different levels of significance in leading the export drive in different developing countries. In the Asian countries they were used largely to bring in technology and marketing expertise to help penetrate foreign markets, since high local savings rates meant there was no marked shortage of finance capital. Consequently, even in the smaller countries such as Singapore, EPZ-based exporters account for a relatively small part of total industrial output and exports. By contrast, in small island countries (e.g. the Dominican Republic, Jamaica and Mauritius) and in large countries where an autarkic industrialization strategy otherwise generally prevailed (e.g. India), EPZs were a way of attracting investment to add to sparse local supplies of capital. Experienced foreign producers were induced to provide the major part of the country's manufactured exports, operating in export enclaves sealed off from the protectionist policies in force elsewhere in the economy.

The export oriented industrialization strategy has been remarkably successful, demonstrating good performance, by any and all economic criteria, including sustained increases in real wages and low rates of unemployment from the 1970s onwards (Turnham, 1995). It has proven successful not only in the East Asian "miracle" countries which first embarked on such policies in a major way, i.e., the Republic of Korea, Taiwan Province of China, Singapore and Hong Kong, but in other countries which followed their example later, such as Malaysia, Thailand and Indonesia in South-East Asia; most recently and spectacularly, China; and Brazil and Mexico in Latin America and Tunisia in North Africa, which together loosely constitute what has been called the "second generation" of NICs (newly industrializing countries). All have promoted export industry and achieved rapid growth in their share of world markets. Latterly India, the last large developing country economy to have remained dedicated to the autarkic model, has liberalized trade and opened its markets to foreign investors. And another group of countries in Eastern Europe, notably Romania and Hungary, have adopted the same approach, promoting the expansion of export industry as their leading sector.

While export production appears to have been the main ingredient or manifestation of the "Asian Miracle", the precise role that export-promotion policy played in the East Asian success story is a matter of keen and continuing debate. The significance of export growth as representing the cause or the effect of general economic growth is disputed, as is the precise role of government policies in the process (Little, 1989 vs. Wade, 1990). The relevance of the Asian experience to other developing countries may also be limited, given the historical conditions specific to East Asia (Riedel, 1993).

Nevertheless, the international financial institutions, notably the World Bank, which set the economic policy reform agenda for borrowing developing countries, have in Structural Adjustment Programmes advocated a trade liberalizing agenda based on a simple model of the East Asian experience, claiming that such policies are conducive to the creation of an internationally competitive industrial sector and inimical to the maintenance of inefficient local industry. Certainly, the experience of many sub-Saharan African countries, which have seen the collapse of local manufacturing capacity and disinvestment by foreign capital, is proof of the latter (Riddell, 1990; Bennell, 1995). But they have not managed to develop any export capacity in non-traditional products. Simple trade liberalizing policies have certainly not on their own been universally effective in promoting exports and growth.

Although the 1960s and 1970s were generally characterized by import substituting industrialization in developing countries, and the 1980s by the spread of market liberalization policies, there has been considerable variation in the timing of the shift away from protected industrialization in different countries. As noted, the East Asian tigers, starting with Hong Kong, were the first to begin active promotion of exports of manufactures in the early 1960s. Some Latin American countries (e.g. Colombia and the Dominican Republic) also began early to explore ways of generating foreign exchange in pockets of non-traditional export production, without changing their generally protectionist policy stance. The result is that at any time a mixture of industrialization policies have been in effect.4 The policy mix has also however reflected the fact that even those countries that most prominently swung over to export promotion did not espouse a simple trade liberalizing, free market approach for the whole of the industrial sector. In particular, large segments of non-exporting manufacturing industry are maintained, often in the state sector and with considerable subsidy, in the East Asian countries, co-existing with the export sector (Riedel, 1993).

These countries have been able to maintain protected and/or subsidized heavy industrial structures in tandem with their exporting sectors because their high domestic savings rates have given them immunity from the dictates of the international financial institutions in matters of economic policy. Their overall industrialization strategy is to foster both export capacity and production capacity in non-competitive but strategically valuable lines in different parts of the industrial sector. The performance of some of the protected industries lends support to the case for long-term infant industry protection — the Republic of Korea exports steel and is a major world shipbuilder, testament to the possibility of eventual attainment of international competitiveness in the heavy industrial field. Most subsidized heavy industry still has virtually no links of any kind with the export sector (Riedel, 1993).

The product categories that have dominated developing countries' export drive in manufactures comprise a range characterized by marked labour intensity of production (Yeats, 1988). Developing countries have achieved a greater share of world markets in these kind of products than in any other. A broad grouping of classic labour intensive, sometimes primary product-based products — comprising clothing, processed foods, drink and tobacco, leather and footwear — exported by developing countries accounted for 24 per cent of world exports in 1989 (UNCTAD, 1992: Annex Table III-1). Clothing remains the classic start-up product for developing country producers to export on their own account. It continues to dominate the manufactures export basket of many of the poorest developing countries. In 1993 clothing accounted for 56 per cent of the merchandise exports of Bangladesh, 49 per cent of Sri Lanka, 53 per cent of Mauritius, and 20 per cent of China (GATT, 1994: Table III.42). In total, clothing accounts for approximately 6 per cent of developing countries' total exports (see Table 1).

Processed food products are another major item, which accounts for a major part of manufactured exports in countries such as Morocco and Bangladesh, although a country's possibility of exporting such products depends on an arbitrary distribution of suitable primary raw materials (e.g. fish and shrimp in these two cases).5 The predominance of such labour intensive items in developing countries' manufactured exports gives empirical support to theories of resource endowments-based comparative advantage as the basis for trade.

Measurement of research and development (R&D) expenditure levels of different industries gives another measure of relative factor use in the production process. R&D measures the expenditure by firms in pursuit of improvements in production technology, which are usually then embodied in changes in machinery and equipment. For this reason high R&D is strongly associated with capital intensity. Developing countries' market share in world trade is much higher in low R&D sectors than in high R&D sectors. They amounted to 24 per cent of low R&D products in 1989, (15 per cent in 1970), compared to 15 per cent in high R & D products in 1989 (compared to 2.5 in 1970) (UNCTAD: 1992, Annex Table III-1).

The perhaps surprisingly high figure for developing countries' share of high R&D product categories has two explanations. First, many of the countries classed among the developing countries have in economic terms in effect graduated from that group, in terms of their per capita income, technological capacity and factor endowment. The composition of their manufactured output has changed accordingly towards more capital intensive, R&D dependent activities.

The second reason relates to the fact that the high R&D product category includes office machines and computers, electronics components and telecommunications equipment. These have been among the fastest growing product groups in world trade. Table 1 illustrates the rapidity of their growth over the period 1980-1981 to 1990-1991. These products have seen their share of developing countries' total exports increase nearly five times over that period, with annual growth rates in export values in some of the component product groups as high as 43 per cent per annum (automatic data processing equipment), 30 per cent per annum (office machinery and automatic data processing equipment parts) and 17 per cent per annum (semi-conductors). (UNCTAD, 1993: Table 4.3). By 1990-1991 electronics exports from developing countries amounted to almost twice the value of clothing exports.

Nevertheless, the difference between these products and the classic export manufactures is more apparent than real with respect to the economic characteristics of the production methods used in developing countries. Much electronics production in developing countries has the peculiar dual characteristic of being both high R&D and labour intensive. Although the electronics industry is, in all its heterogeneity, essentially the bearer of the modern technological revolution and has extremely high R&D levels, production of electronics products involves many distinct and separable activities. The work carried out in developing countries concerns only a small part of the total range of production activities. It mainly consists of assembly-type operations, using imported components, with factor use ratios at the labour intensive end of the range. Simple cost considerations dictated that electronics companies, right from the beginning, located them in lower wage countries, by analogy with the world distribution of production capacity in clothing and other technologically simple labour intensive processes. The growth of electronics in developing countries' manufactures exports does not disturb the explanatory power of the comparative advantage model.

The differing technological level of the clothing and electronics industries does however have other consequences. The high R&D level of the electronics industry is reflected in its dominance worldwide by giant Northern-based TNCs, which have the organizational capacity to seek cost savings by scattering integral parts of the production process. By contrast, the clothing industry, in which R&D levels are low, includes many more indigenous developing country producers. In the few cases where TNCs are present in this industry, they are small or medium sized and sometimes based in developing countries themselves (United Nations, 1994). International production links certainly exist in the clothing industry, but they tend to take the form of sub-contracts between separately owned firms, rather than command chains between head offices and subsidiaries of TNCs.6

The labour intensity of clothing and other classic manufactures exports has two corollaries. First, the relatively small capital commitment required makes for ease of entry to the sector by new firms. There is little place in this sector, on the domestic or world level, for collusive behaviour or restrictive business practices by established firms to keep out new entrants. Market conditions as well as the low level of technology therefore make international markets in these products a prime candidate for indigenous competitors from new source locations. This is not to say that technology in this sector is static. There are quite marked changes over time in the ranking of countries' unit labour costs (see Table 2), which reflect changes in both wage rates and labour productivity (United Nations, 1994a). Even so, rises in labour productivity in these ("light") product categories tend to lag significantly behind those in other ("heavy") parts of industry (UNCTAD, 1993). Technical progress, although real, has therefore not undermined the relative labour intensity of clothing production within the modern industrial sector.

The second corollary has to do with the nature of employment in these sectors and the characteristics of the sectoral workforce, to which we now turn.

3 Support for these assertions is found in the following sections.

4 Pearson (1992), while pointing correctly to the complexity of the situation, perhaps goes too far in denying any historical progression from autarkic to export oriented industrial strategies. Such a transition can be said in any event to be predicated within the autarkic approach.

5 It may be because of this absolute link with the presence of particular primary resources that the food processing industry seems to have received much less research attention in the international trade literature than its importance to developing countries as a source of exports warrants.

6 This is based on case study evidence; no estimate of the overall share of sub-contracted production or of production by TNC subsidiaries in developing countries' total exports of clothing is available.


Previous              Next              Contents